What Is the Money Supply?

The U.S. money supply comprises currency—dollar bills and coins issued by the Federal Reserve System and the U.S. Treasury—and diverse kinds of deposits held past the public at commercial banks and other depository institutions such as thrifts and credit unions. On June xxx, 2004, the coin supply, measured as the sum of currency and checking account deposits, totaled $1,333 billion. Including some types of savings deposits, the money supply totaled $half-dozen,275 billion. An even broader measure totaled $9,275 billion.

These measures correspond to three definitions of money that the Federal Reserve uses: M1, a narrow measure of money'due south function as a medium of commutation; M2, a broader measure that also reflects money's function equally a store of value; and M3, a yet broader measure that covers items that many regard every bit close substitutes for coin.

The definition of money has varied. For centuries, physical commodities, almost commonly silver or golden, served equally money. Subsequently, when paper money and checkable deposits were introduced, they were convertible into commodity coin. The abandonment of convertibility of money into a commodity since Baronial 15, 1971, when President Richard G. Nixon discontinued converting U.Southward. dollars into gold at $35 per ounce, has fabricated the monies of the U.s. and other countries into fiat money—money that national monetary authorities accept the power to issue without legal constraints.

Why Is the Money Supply Of import?

Because coin is used in virtually all economic transactions, it has a powerful consequence on economical activity. An increase in the supply of money works both through lowering interest rates, which spurs investment, and through putting more than money in the easily of consumers, making them experience wealthier, and thus stimulating spending. Business firms respond to increased sales by ordering more than raw materials and increasing production. The spread of concern activity increases the need for labor and raises the need for capital goods. In a buoyant economic system, stock market prices rising and firms issue equity and debt. If the money supply continues to expand, prices begin to rise, especially if output growth reaches capacity limits. As the public begins to expect inflation, lenders insist on higher involvement rates to offset an expected decline in purchasing power over the life of their loans.

Opposite furnishings occur when the supply of coin falls or when its rate of growth declines. Economic activeness declines and either disinflation (reduced inflation) or deflation (falling prices) results.

What Determines the Coin Supply?

Federal Reserve policy is the near of import determinant of the money supply. The Federal Reserve affects the money supply by affecting its most important component, bank deposits.

Here is how it works. The Federal Reserve requires depository institutions (commercial banks and other financial institutions) to concord every bit reserves a fraction of specified deposit liabilities. Depository institutions hold these reserves as greenbacks in their vaults or Automatic Teller Machines (ATMs) and as deposits at Federal Reserve banks. In plow, the Federal Reserve controls reserves past lending money to depository institutions and changing the Federal Reserve discount rate on these loans and by open-market operations. The Federal Reserve uses open-market operations to either increment or decrease reserves. To increase reserves, the Federal Reserve buys U.S. Treasury securities by writing a check drawn on itself. The seller of the treasury security deposits the check in a bank, increasing the seller's deposit. The bank, in turn, deposits the Federal Reserve check at its commune Federal Reserve bank, thus increasing its reserves. The opposite sequence occurs when the Federal Reserve sells treasury securities: the purchaser's deposits fall, and, in turn, the bank's reserves fall.

If the Federal Reserve increases reserves, a single bank can brand loans up to the amount of its excess reserves, creating an equal corporeality of deposits. The banking system, however, tin create a multiple expansion of deposits. As each bank lends and creates a deposit, it loses reserves to other banks, which use them to increment their loans and thus create new deposits, until all backlog reserves are used up.

If the required reserve ratio is ten percent, and so starting with new reserves of, say, $1,000, the most a bank tin can lend is $900, since it must keep $100 as reserves against the deposit it simultaneously sets up. When the borrower writes a check against this amount in his banking concern A, the payee deposits information technology in his bank B. Each new demand deposit that a bank receives creates an equal amount of new reserves. Depository financial institution B will now have additional reserves of $900, of which it must keep $90 in reserves, then information technology tin lend out simply $810. The total of new loans the banking system every bit a whole grants in this instance will exist 10 times the initial amount of excess reserve, or $9,000: 900 + 810 + 729 + 656.1 + 590.5, so on.

In a system with fractional reserve requirements, an increase in bank reserves can back up a multiple expansion of deposits, and a decrease tin result in a multiple wrinkle of deposits. The value of the multiplier depends on the required reserve ratio on deposits. A high required-reserve ratio lowers the value of the multiplier. A low required-reserve ratio raises the value of the multiplier.

In 2004, banks with a total of $vii million in checkable deposits were exempt from reserve requirements. Those with more than $seven million only less than $47.6 million in checkable deposits were required to continue three percent of such accounts as reserves, while those with checkable accounts amounting to $47.6 meg or more were required to proceed 10 per centum. No reserves were required to exist held against time deposits.

Even if there were no legal reserve requirements for banks, they would still maintain required immigration balances as reserves with the Federal Reserve, whose ability to command the volume of deposits would not be impaired. Banks would continue to go along reserves to enable them to clear debits arising from transactions with other banks, to obtain currency to meet depositors' demands, and to avert a deficit equally a event of imbalances in clearings.

The currency component of the coin supply, using the M2 definition of money, is far smaller than the deposit component. Currency includes both Federal Reserve notes and coins. The Board of Governors places an order with the U.Due south. Bureau of Engraving and Printing for Federal Reserve notes for all the Reserve Banks and and then allocates the notes to each district Reserve Bank. Currently, the notes are no longer marked with the private district seal. The Federal Reserve Banks typically hold the notes in their vaults until sold at face value to commercial banks, which pay private carriers to selection up the cash from their district Reserve Bank.

The Reserve Banks debit the commercial banks' reserve accounts as payment for the notes their customers demand. When the demand for notes falls, the Reserve Banks accept a return flow of the notes from the commercial banks and credit their reserves.

The U.South. mints pattern and manufacture U.S. coins for distribution to Federal Reserve Banks. The Board of Governors places orders with the appropriate mints. The system buys coin at its face value by crediting the U.S. Treasury'southward account at the Reserve Banks. The Federal Reserve System holds its coins in 190 money terminals, which armored carrier companies own and operate. Commercial banks buy coins at face value from the Reserve Banks, which receive payment by debiting the commercial banks' reserve accounts. The commercial banks pay the full costs of aircraft the coin.

In a fractional reserve banking system, drains of currency from banks reduce their reserves, and unless the Federal Reserve provides acceptable additional amounts of currency and reserves, a multiple contraction of deposits results, reducing the quantity of money. Currency and bank reserves added together equal the monetary base of operations, sometimes known equally high-powered money. The Federal Reserve has the power to command the issue of both components. By adjusting the levels of banks' reserve balances, over several quarters it can accomplish a desired rate of growth of deposits and of the money supply. When the public and the banks modify the ratio of their currency and reserves to deposits, the Federal Reserve can outset the result on the money supply by irresolute reserves and/or currency.

If the Federal Reserve determines the magnitude of the money supply, what makes the nominal value of coin in existence equal to the amount people want to hold? A change in interest rates is one way to make that correspondence happen. A autumn in involvement rates increases the corporeality of money people wish to concord, while a rise in interest rates decreases that amount. A modify in prices is another way to make the coin supply equal the amount demanded. When people hold more than nominal dollars than they want, they spend them faster, causing prices to rise. These ascension prices reduce the purchasing power of money until the amount people want equals the amount available. Conversely, when people hold less coin than they want, they spend more slowly, causing prices to autumn. Every bit a consequence, the real value of money in existence just equals the amount people are willing to concord.

Irresolute Federal Reserve Techniques

The Federal Reserve'south techniques for achieving its desired level of reserves—both borrowed reserves that banks obtain at the discount window and nonborrowed reserves that it provides by open-market place purchases—have inverse significantly over fourth dimension. At beginning, the Federal Reserve controlled the volume of reserves and of borrowing past fellow member banks mainly by irresolute the disbelieve charge per unit. It did so on the theory that borrowed reserves made fellow member banks reluctant to extend loans because their desire to repay their ain indebtedness to the Federal Reserve as soon as possible was supposed to inhibit their willingness to accommodate borrowers. In the 1920s, when the Federal Reserve discovered that open-market place operations also created reserves, changing nonborrowed reserves offered a more effective mode to offset undesired changes in borrowing by member banks. In the 1950s, the Federal Reserve sought to command what are called complimentary reserves, or backlog reserves minus member banking concern borrowing.

The Fed has interpreted a ascension in involvement rates as tighter monetary policy and a fall every bit easier monetary policy. But interest rates are an imperfect indicator of budgetary policy. If easy monetary policy is expected to crusade inflation, lenders need a higher interest rate to compensate for this aggrandizement, and borrowers are willing to pay a higher charge per unit because inflation reduces the value of the dollars they repay. Thus, an increase in expected inflation increases involvement rates. Between 1977 and 1979, for example, U.S. monetary policy was easy and interest rates rose. Similarly, if tight budgetary policy is expected to reduce inflation, interest rates could fall.

From 1979 to 1982, when Paul Volcker was chairman of the Federal Reserve, the Fed tried to control nonborrowed reserves to achieve its monetary target. The procedure produced large swings in both coin growth and involvement rates. Forcing nonborrowed reserves to decline when in a higher place target led borrowed reserves to ascent because the Federal Reserve allowed banks access to the discount window when they sought this alternative source of reserves. Since and so, the Federal Reserve has specified a narrow range for the federal funds rate, the interest rate on overnight loans from one bank to another, as the instrument to reach its objectives. Although the Fed does not directly transact in the Fed funds market, when the Federal Reserve specifies a higher Fed funds rate, it makes this college rate stick by reducing the reserves it provides the entire fiscal organization. When it specifies a lower Fed funds rate, it makes this stick by providing increased reserves. The Fed funds market rate deviates minimally from the target rate. If the divergence is greater, that is a bespeak to the Fed that the reserves it has provided are non consistent with the funds charge per unit it has appear. It will increase or reduce the reserves depending on the divergence.

The big change in Federal Reserve objectives under Alan Greenspan's chairmanship was the acquittance that its key responsibility is to command inflation. The Federal Reserve adopted an implicit target for projected hereafter inflation. Its success in meeting its target has gained information technology credibility. The target has become the public'southward expected inflation rate.

History of the U.S. Coin Supply

From the founding of the Federal Reserve in 1913 until the cease of Earth War Ii, the money supply tended to grow at a college rate than the growth of nominal GNP. This increment in the ratio of money supply to GNP shows an increase in the amount of money every bit a fraction of their income that people wanted to concur. From 1946 to 1980, nominal GNP tended to abound at a college rate than the growth of the coin supply, an indication that the public reduced its coin balances relative to income. Until 1986, money balances grew relative to income; since then they take declined relative to income. Economists explain these movements by changes in price expectations, as well equally by changes in interest rates that make money holding more or less expensive. If prices are expected to fall, the inducement to hold money balances rises since money will buy more if the expectations are realized; similarly, if involvement rates fall, the price of holding money balances rather than spending or investing them declines. If prices are expected to rise or interest rates ascension, property coin rather than spending or investing it becomes more than costly.

Since 1914 a sustained decline of the money supply has occurred during merely three business organisation cycle contractions, each of which was astringent as judged by the decline in output and rise in unemployment: 1920–1921, 1929–1933, and 1937–1938. The severity of the economical turn down in each of these cyclical downturns, information technology is widely accepted, was a consequence of the reduction in the quantity of money, particularly so for the downturn that began in 1929, when the quantity of money brutal by an unprecedented one-third. There have been no sustained declines in the quantity of money in the past six decades.

The United States has experienced iii major cost inflations since 1914, and each has been preceded and accompanied by a respective increase in the rate of growth of the money supply: 1914–1920, 1939–1948, and 1967–1980. An dispatch of money growth in backlog of real output growth has invariably produced inflation—in these episodes and in many earlier examples in the Us and elsewhere in the globe.

Until the Federal Reserve adopted an implicit inflation target in the 1990s, the coin supply tended to rise more than rapidly during business cycle expansions than during business wheel contractions. The rate of rise tended to autumn before the peak in business and to increment before the trough. Prices rose during expansions and vicious during contractions. This pattern is currently non observed. Growth rates of money aggregates tend to be moderate and stable, although the Federal Reserve, like almost key banks, now ignores money aggregates in its framework and practice. A possibly unintended result of its success in decision-making inflation is that coin aggregates have no predictive power with respect to prices.

The lesson that the history of money supply teaches is that to ignore the magnitude of money supply changes is to court monetary disorder. Time volition tell whether the current budgetary nirvana is enduring and a challenge to that lesson.


Well-nigh the Author

Anna J. Schwartz is an economist at the National Bureau of Economic Research in New York. She is a distinguished fellow of the American Economic Association.


Further Reading

Eatwell, John, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, eds. Money: The New Palgrave. New York: Norton, 1989.

Friedman, Milton. Monetary Mischief: Episodes in Monetary History. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1992.

Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. A Monetary History of the U.s., 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.

McCallum, Bennett T. Budgetary Economics. New York: Macmillan, 1989.

Meltzer, Allan H. A History of the Federal Reserve. Vol. i: 1913–1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Printing, 2003.

Rasche, Robert H., and James M. Johannes. Controlling the Growth of Monetary Aggregates. Rochester Studies in Economies and Policy Problems. Boston: Kluwer, 1987.

Schwartz, Anna J. Money in Historical Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1987.